Fact: Most big businesses are not monopolies and not all monopolies are big business.
Take cranberry juice. How do we know that the price being charged is not far above their
costs of production? We don’t. We actually have no idea of how much it costs to
produce a bottle or can of cranberry juice.
Competition makes it unnecessary for us to know. If the price of apple juice is higher
than necessary to compensate for the costs incurred in producing it, the result is a high
rate of profit. Only, this is never done in a vacuum. Word gets out that there is a lot of
money to be made in cranberry juice. This automatically attracts more investment into
the cranberry juice industry creating more competition. Eventually, these additional
competitors will drive prices down to a level that compensates the costs with the same
average rate of return on similar investment available elsewhere. When that happens, the
in-flow of investments from other sectors of the economy stop. The incentive of a high
rate of profit has evaporated and it doesn’t make sense to these investors to put any more
money into it. They will now put there money in other high rate of profit opportunities
until those, too come back to reality
Let’s say there was a monopoly in the production of cranberry juice. One company had
all the cranberries. The entire process would not take place.
What adversely affects the total wealth in the economy as a whole is the effect of a
monopoly on the allocation of scarce resources which have alternative uses.
When a monopoly charges a higher price than it could charge if it had competition,
consumers tend to buy less of the product than they would at a lower competitive price.
In short, a monopolist produces less output than a competitive industry would produce
with the same available resources, technology and cost conditions. The monopolist stops
short at a point where consumers are still willing to pay enough to cover the cost of
production (including a normal profit) of more output because the monopolist is charging
more than the usual profit.
Monopolies result in the economy’s resources being used inefficiently, because these
resources would be transferred from more valued uses to less valued uses.
Similar principles apply to a cartel – that is, a group of businesses, which agree among
themselves to charge higher prices or otherwise avoid competing with one another. In
practice, individual members of the cartel tend to cheat on one another secretly –
lowering the cartel price to some customers in order to take business away from other
members of the cartel. When this becomes widespread, the cartel becomes irrelevant.
(OPEC is a perfect example.)
Because cartels were once known as “trusts”, legislation designed to outlaw monopolies
and cartels became known as “anti-trust” laws. Hence the Sherman Anti-Trust Act of
1890.
Where a monopoly or cartel maintains prices that produce higher than normal profits,
other businesses are attracted to the industry. This additional competition then tends to
force prices and profits down. (No different than the cranberry juice producers.)
When railroads were first built in the 19th Century, the Interstate Commerce Commission
had to be created to regulate them. The same was true for the Federal Communications
Commission regarding the telephone companies.
The intent was to have a regulatory commission set prices where they would have been if
there were a competitive marketplace. The reality of the situation is that there is no way
to know what those prices would be. Only the actual functioning of a market itself could
reveal such prices, resulting in the less efficient firms being eliminated by bankruptcy and
only the most efficient surviving.
The most that a regulatory agency can do is accept what appear to be reasonable
production costs and allow the monopoly to make what seems to be a reasonable profit
over and above such costs.
Genuine plunder of one nation or people by another has been all too common throughout human history. During the era before the First World War, when Germany had colonies in Africa, only 4 of its 22 enterprises with cocoa plantations there paid dividends, as did only 8 of 58 rubber plantations and only 3 out of 49 diamond mining companies. At the height of the British Empire in the early twentieth century, the British invested more in the United States than in all of Asia and Africa put together. Quite simply, there was more wealth to be made from rich countries than from poor countries. For similar reasons, throughout most of the twentieth century the United States invested more in Canada than in Asia and Africa put together. Only the rise of prosperous Asian industrial nations in the latter part of the twentieth century attracted more American investors in that part of the world. Perhaps the strongest evidence against the economic significance of colonies in the modern world is tha
Comments
Post a Comment